Javascript is required
Agrawal, A. and Jaffe, J. (2000). The post-merger performance puzzle. Advances in Mergers and Acquisitions 1, 7-41.
Agrawal, A., Jaffe, J. and Mandelker, G. (1992). The post-merger performance of acquiring firms: a re-examination of an anomaly. Journal of Finance 47, 1605-1621.
Alexandridis, G., Mavrovitis, C. and Travlos, N. (2012). How have MandAs changed? Evidence from the sixth merger wave. European Journal of Finance 18, 663-688.
Al-Sharkas, A. (2003). Shareholder wealth effect in bank mergers: new evidence during the period 1980-2000. In 2003 Proceedings from AFFI, Paris. [Google Scholar]
Amihud, Y. and Lev, B. (1981). Risk reduction as a managerial motive for conglomerate mergers. Bell Journal of Economics 12, 605-617.
Auerbach, A. and Reishaus, D. (1987). The effects of taxation on the merger decision. National Bureau of Economic Research, Working paper.
Asquith, P., Bruner, R. F. and Mullins, D.W. (1983). The gains to bidding firms from mergers. Journal of Financial Economics 11, 121-139.
Berkovitch, E. and Narayanan, M. (1993). Motives for takeovers: an empirical investigation. Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis 28, 347-362. [Google Scholar]
Blume, M. (1979). Betas and their regression tendencies: some further evidence. Journal of Finance 34, 265-267. [Google Scholar]
Bradley, M., Desai, A. and Kim, H.E. (1988). Synergistic gains from corporate acquisitions and their division between the stockholders of target and acquiring firms. Journal of Financial Economics 21, 3-40.
Bradley, M and Sundaram, A. (2004). Do acquisitions drive performance or does performance drive acquisitions? SSRN Working paper.
Bruner, R. (2004). Does MandA pay? Applied Mergers and Acquisitions 1, 11-15.
Chappell, H. and Cheng, D. (1984). Firms’ acquisition decisions and Tobin’s Q ratio. Journal of Economics and Business 2, 29-42.
Conn, R., Cosh, A., Guest, P. and Hughes, A. (2005). The impact on UK acquiriers of domestic, cross-border, public and private acquisitions. Journal of Business Finance and Accounting 32, 815-870.
Dennis, D. and McConnell, J. (1986). Corporate mergers and security returns. Journal of Financial Economics 16, 143-187.
Dodd, P. and Ruback, R. (1977). Tender offers and shareholders returns: an empirical analysis. Journal of Financial Economics 5, 351-374. [Google Scholar]
Doukas, J., Holmen, M. and Travlos, N. (2002). Diversification, ownership, and control of Swedish corporations. European Financial Management 8, 281-314.
Eckbo, E. (1992). Mergers and the value of antitrust dererrence. Journal of Finance 47, 1005-1029.
Faccio, M., McDonnell, J. and Stolin, D. (2006). Returns to acquirers of listed and unlisted targets. Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis 41, 197-220.
Fishman, M. (1988). A theory of preemptive takeover bidding. Rand Journal of Economics 19, 88-101. [Google Scholar]
Galai, D. and Masulis, R. (1976). The option pricing model and the risk factor of stock. Journal of Financial Economics 4, 53-82.
Goergen, M., Martynova, M. and Renneboog, L. (2005). Corporate governance convergence: evidence from takeover regulation reforms. Oxford Review of Economic Policy 21, 243-268. [Google Scholar]
Goergen, M. and Renneboog, L. (2004). Shareholders wealth effects of European domestic and cross-border bids. European Financial Management 10, 9-45.
Grossman, S. and Hart, O. (1980). Takeover bids, the free rider problem, and the theory of the corporation. Bell Journal of Economics 11, 42-64.
Hamza, T. (2011). Determinants of short-term value creation for the bidder: evidence from France. Journal of Management and Governance 15, 157-186. [Google Scholar]
Hansen, R. (1987). A theory for the choice of exchange medium in mergers and acquisitions. Journal of Business 60, 75-95. [Google Scholar]
Harris, E. (1990). Anti-takeover measures, golden parachutes, and target firm shareholder welfare. Rand Journal of Economics 21, 614-625. [Google Scholar]
Högfeldt, P. and Högholm, K. (2000). A law and finance theory of strategic blocking and preemptive bidding in takeovers. Journal of Corporate Finance 6, 403-425.
Israel, R. (1992). Capital and ownership structures, and the market for corporate control. The Review of Financial Studies 5, 181-198. [Google Scholar]
Jarrell, G., Brickley, J. and Netter, J. (1988). The market for corporate control: the empirical evidence since 1980. Journal of Economic Perspectives 2, 49-68. [Google Scholar]
Jensen, M. (1986). Agency cost of free cash flow, corporate finance and takeovers. American Economic Review 76, 323-329. [Google Scholar]
Jensen, M. (2004). The agency cost of overvalued equity and the current state of corporate finance. European Financial Management 10, 549-565. [Google Scholar]
Jensen, M. andMeckling, W. (1976). Theory of the firm: managerial behavior, agency costs and ownership structure. Journal of Financial Economics 3, 305-360. [Google Scholar]
Jensen, M. and Ruback, R. (1983). The market for corporate control: the scientific evidence. Journal of Financial Economics 11, 5-50. [Google Scholar]
Kane, E. (2000). Incentives for banking megamergers: what motives might regulators infer from event-study evidence? Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 32, 671-701.
La Porta, R., Lopez-de-Silanes, F., Shleifer, A. and Vishny, R. (2002). Investor protection and corporate valuation. Journal of Finance 57, 1147-1170.
Lakonishok, J., Shleifer, A. and Vishny, R. (1994). Contrarian investment, extrapolation, and risk. Journal of Finance 49, 1541-1578.
Levy, H. and Sarnat, M. (1970). Diversification, portfolio analysis and the uneasy case for conglomerate mergers. Journal of Finance 25, 795-802.
Malmendier, U. and Tate, G. (2005). Does overconfidence affect corporate investment? CEO overconfidence measures revisited. European Financial Management 11, 649-659.
Martynova, M. and Renneboog, L. (2008a). A century of corporate takeovers: what have we learned and where do we stand? Journal of Banking and Finance 32, 2148-2177. [Google Scholar]
Martynova, M. and Renneboog, L. (2008b). Spillover of corporate governance standards in cross-border mergers and acquisitions. Journal of Corporate Finance 14, 200-223.
Martynova, M. and Renneboog, L. (2009). What determines the financing decision in corporate takeovers: cost of capital, agency problems or the means of payment? Journal of Corporate Finance 15, 290-315. [Google Scholar]
Martynova, M. and Renneboog, L. (2011). The performance of the European market for corporate control: evidence from the fifth takeover wave. European Financial Management 17, 208-259. [Google Scholar]
Moeller, S. and Schlingemann, F. (2005). Global diversification and bidder gains: a comparison between cross-border and domestic acquisitions. Journal of Banking and Finance 29, 533-564. [Google Scholar]
Moeller, S., Schlingemann, F. and Stulz, R. (2004). Firm size and the gain from acquisitions. Journal of Financial Economics 73, 201-228.
Moeller, S., Schlingemann, F. and Stulz, R. (2005). Wealth destruction on a massive scale? A study of acquiring-firm returns in the recent merger wave. Journal of Finance 60, 757-782.
Morck, R., Shleifer, A. and Vishny, R.W. (1990). Do managerial objectives drive bad acquisitions? Journal of Finance 45, 31-48.
Myers, S. and Majluf, N. (1984). Corporate financing and investment decisions when firms have information that investors do not have. Journal of Financial Economics 13, 187-221.
Prescott, E. and Visscher, M. (1980). Organization capital. Journal of Political Economy 88, 446-461.
Rau, R. and Vermaelen, T. (1998). Glamour, value and post-acquisition performance of acquiring firms. Journal of Financial Economics 49, 223-253.
Roll, R. (1986). The hubris hypothesis of corporate takeovers. The Journal of Business 59, 197-216. [Google Scholar]
Scharfstein, D. and Stein, J. (2000). The dark side of internal capital markets: divisional rent-seeking and inefficient investment. Journal of Finance 55, 2537-2564. [Google Scholar]
Shleifer, A. and Summers, L. (1988). Breach of trust in hostile takeovers. In Corporate takeovers: causes and consequences, University of Chicago Press, Chicago. [Google Scholar]
Shleifer, A. and Vichny, R. (1989). Managerial entrenchment: the case of managerial-specific investments. Journal of Financial Economics 25, 123-139. [Google Scholar]
Stulz, R., Walking, R. and Song, M. (1990). The distribution of target ownership and the division of gains in successful takeovers. Journal of Finance 45, 817-833.
Sudarsanam, S. and Mahate, A. (2003). Glamour acquirers, method of payment and post-acquisition performance: the UK evidence. Journal of Business Finance and Accounting 30, 299-341.
Summer, C. (1980). Strategic behavior in business and government. Little, Brown and Company, Boston. [Google Scholar]
Tang, T. (2015). Bidder’s gain: Evidence from termination returns. International Review of Finance, 15, 457-487. [Google Scholar]
Travlos, N. G. (1987). Corporate takeover bids, methods of payment, and bidding firms’ stock returns. Journal of Finance 42, 943-963. [Google Scholar]
Williamson, O. (1975). Markets and hierarchies: analysis and antitrust implications. Free press, New York. [Google Scholar]
Search
Open Access
Research article

Short Term Announcement Returns to the Bidder**

kenneth högholm*,
johan knif
HANKEN School of Economics, PO Box 287, FIN-65101 Vaasa, FINLAND
Journal of Corporate Governance, Insurance, and Risk Management
|
Volume 3, Issue 2, 2016
|
Pages 17-45
Received: 03-21-2016,
Revised: 07-12-2016,
Accepted: 07-26-2016,
Available online: 08-29-2016
View Full Article|Download PDF

Abstract:

In this paper we investigate the short term abnormal return to the bidding firm’s shareholders in takeover transactions in Finland during the time period from January 2000 to December 2013. Specific features of the market for corporate acquisitions in Finland are that almost all of the transactions are friendly acquisitions and usually aim for 100 % of the target company. We estimate the abnormal return around 314 individual takeover announcements and investigate determinants of the abnormal returns. Our results show that the takeover announcement on average yields a positive abnormal return to the bidding firm’s shareholders, thus, support the value creating hypothesis. The announcement effect on the announcement day is1.4 % and statistically significant. Both pre-event and post-event abnormal returns are statistically insignificant, although there is sign of a negative revaluation in the post-event period. Among the takeover characteristics, we document a significant impact on the bidder’s abnormal return on the announcement day for small deals yielding a higher abnormal return, but a positive relationship between the announcement effect and the relative size of the deal, cross-border deals giving a smaller abnormal return, and indication of diversification deals giving a higher abnormal return to the bidder’s shareholders.

Keywords: Event study, Market model, Takeover, Target size, Value creation

1. Introduction

Corporate acquisition is a fast way for a company to grow compared to organic growth. Most bidding companies motivate this way to grow by the potential synergies that the acquisition creates, hence, one should expect the acquisition not only to create growth but also to create value for the acquiring firm’s shareholders. However, empirical evidence from the takeover market report that bidding firm’s shareholders mostly earn small and insignificant returns, while target firm’s shareholders earn large and significant returns in takeover transactions.1 The returns are heavily skewed in favor of the target firm also after adjusting for differences in firm size. Bradley, Desai and Kim (1988) reported a 90/10 split of the value-weighted takeover gain in their US sample, while Högfeldt and Högholm (2000) observed a similar distribution in a sample of Swedish takeovers.

Several hypotheses have emerged trying to explain these empirical findings. Some suggest that takeovers do create value, but that the target firm’s shareholders for some reason obtain a larger share of the gain. Grossman and Hart’s (1980) free riding problem is one explanation. In the extreme case the free riding hypothesis suggests that target shareholders capture the entire gain. Alternatively, e.g., competition among bidders (Fishman (1980)), takeover defense measures (H​a​r​r​i​s​ ​(​1​9​9​0​)), or target ownership structure (Högfeldt and Högholm (2000)) may also explain the skewed distribution in favor of the target firm’s shareholders.

Another line of thought suggests that takeovers do not create any additional value, but is more of a redistribution of wealth from shareholders in the bidding firm to shareholders in the target firm. Hence, takeovers occur because of management incentives or mistakes, i.e., takeovers occur because management of bidding firms wishes to grow (e.g., Morck, Shleifer and Vishny (1990)), or they overestimate the value of the target firm (e.g., R​o​l​l​ ​(​1​9​8​6​)). Alternatively, the management of the bidding firm takes advantage of a temporary misvaluation of the firm, hence, taking advantage of a window of opportunity to make an acquisition (e.g., J​e​n​s​e​n​ ​(​2​0​0​4​)).

The purpose of this study is to investigate the short-term abnormal return to the bidding firm’s shareholders in takeover transactions made by Finnish stock market listed companies during the time period from January 2000 to December 2013. To our knowledge there are very few studies looking at the Finnish takeover market, and none looking at the market during the last 15 years. Specific features of the market for corporate acquisitions in Finland are that almost all of the transactions are friendly acquisitions and usually aim for 100 % of the target company. We estimate the abnormal return around 314 individual takeover announcements and investigate determinants of the abnormal returns. Our results show that the takeover announcement on average yields a positive abnormal return to the bidding firm’s shareholders, thus, support the value creating hypothesis. The announcement effect on the announcement day is 1.4 % and statistically significant. Both pre-event and post-event abnormal returns are statistically insignificant, although there is sign of a negative revaluation in the post-event period. Among the takeover characteristics, we document a significant impact on the bidder’s abnormal return on the announcement day for small deals yielding a higher abnormal return, but a positive relationship between the announcement effect and the relative size of the deal, cross-border deals giving a smaller abnormal return, and an indication of diversification deals giving a higher abnormal return to the bidder’s shareholders.

The reminder of the paper is organized as follows. Section 2 summarizes the literature review on the motivations for takeovers and the determinants of the share price reaction to the takeover announcement. Section 3 describes the methodology and the data, while the empirical results are presented in Section 4. Section 5 concludes the study.

2. Motives for Takeovers

Three major takeover motives have been advanced in the literature implying gains for both the bidder and the target, or negative return to the bidder. These are the synergy motive, the agency motive and the hubris hypothesis.

The synergy motive assumes that managers maximize shareholders’ wealth and would engage in takeover activities only if it results in gains to the shareholders. Among the synergy motives, the first set of motives is consistent with the assumption that additional value is created by takeovers. The second set of motives cast doubt on whether any additional value is created by takeovers, or if the resulting gains to shareholders’ is at the expense of other stakeholders (e.g., employees, customers, suppliers, tax payers).

According to the inefficient management motive, more efficient firms will acquire less efficient firms and realize gains by improving their efficiency; this implies excess managerial capabilities in the acquiring firm (e.g., Bradley, Desai and Kim (1988)). The operating synergy motive postulates, e.g., economics of scale and that takeovers help achieve levels of activities at which they can be obtained (e.g., W​i​l​l​i​a​m​s​o​n​ ​(​1​9​7​5​)). The financial synergy motive hypothesizes complementaries between merging firms, not in managerial capabilities, but in the availability of investment opportunities and internal cash flows. A merged firm will have lower cost of capital due to lower cost of internal funds as well as possible risk reduction, savings in flotation costs, and improvements in capital allocation (e.g., Levy and Sarnat (1970), Galai and Masulis (1976), Prescott and Visscher (1980)).

The theory of strategic alignment to changing environments motivates takeovers to take place as a response to environmental changes. External acquisitions of needed capabilities allow firms to adapt more quickly to changes, than by developing capabilities internally (e.g., S​u​m​m​e​r​ ​(​1​9​8​0​)). The undervaluation theory states that takeovers occur when the market value of the target firm for some reason does not reflect its true or potential value, or its value in the hands of an alternative management. Firms can acquire assets for expansion more cheaply by buying the stock of existing firms than by buying or building the assets, when the target's stock price is below the replacement cost of its assets (e.g., Chappell and Cheng (1984)). In line with the undervaluation hypothesis, the information or signaling theory attempts to explain why target shares seem to be permanently revalued upward in a takeover whether or not it is successful. The information hypothesis states that the takeover sends a signal to the market that the target shares are undervalued, or alternatively, the offer signals information to target management which inspires them to implement a more efficient strategy on their own (e.g., Dodd and Ruback (1977), Bradley, Desai and Kim (1988)).

All of the above presented motives suggest that additional value is created in takeovers. The remaining three motives argue that the gains accruing to target and bidder shareholders are merely wealth redistribution from other stakeholders in the respective firms. The market power hypothesis states that shareholder's wealth increases at the expense of customers (or suppliers), due to increased concentration leading to collusion and monopoly effects (e.g., Eckbo (1992)). Redistribution of wealth is also the case if takeovers are motivated by tax considerations. In this case, shareholders gain at the expense of tax payers (e.g., Auerbach and Reishaus (1987)). Finally, according to the redistribution hypothesis, shareholders’ gain can also accrue from bondholders due to unexpectedly increased leverage (e.g., Dennis andMcConnel (1986)), or from employees, who are deprived of their benefits (e.g., Shleifer and Summers (1988)).

According to the synergy motives, there should always be a positive gain in takeovers for all shareholders, stemming from efficiency improvements or from other stakeholders. Therefore, it follows that the measured gain to both target and bidder shareholders is expected to be positive. The division of the gain between target firm and acquiring firm shareholders may, though, not be equally distributed, but may be skewed in favor of the target due to a number of reasons. Grossman and Hart (1980) argue that due to potential free riding by the target firm's atomistic shareholders, the smallest tender offer price the shareholders will accept is the full improvement value after a successful takeover by the bidder. Hence, the extreme case of the free riding problem suggests that the target captures the entire gain, and consequently, there is no incentive to make takeover bids at all. F​i​s​h​m​a​n​ ​(​1​9​8​8​), among others, offers bidder competition as one reason for a larger target share of the takeover gain. On the other hand, H​a​r​r​i​s​ ​(​1​9​9​0​) argues that takeover defense measures, taken by the target firm's management, force the bidder to pay out a large share of the gain to target shareholders. Another reason for a larger target share of the gain is an upward-sloping supply curve as a result of heterogeneity in beliefs and differences in tax status, as suggested by, e.g., Stulz, Walking and Song (1990). Finally, one line of thought suggests that if the target has some bargaining power, mainly because it can resist the bidder, target shareholders may be able to extract a larger fraction of the takeover gain in an explicit or implicit negotiation with the bidder (e.g., I​s​r​a​e​l​ ​(​1​9​9​2​), Högfeldt and Högholm (2000)).

According to the agency theory (Jensen and Meckling (1976), J​e​n​s​e​n​ ​(​1​9​8​6​)) it has been suggested that some takeovers are primarily motivated by the self-interest of the acquirer management. Several reasons have been advanced to explain this divergence. Among them are diversification of management's personal portfolio (Amihud and Lev (1981), use of free cash flow to increase the size of the firm (J​e​n​s​e​n​ ​(​1​9​8​6​)), and acquiring assets that increase the firm's dependence on the management ((Shleifer and Vishny (1989)). The basic idea in most of these explanations is that acquisitions result in an extraction of value from the acquirer shareholders by acquirer management.

The important aspect of the above argument is that the target firm has been identified by the acquirer management as one that is most suited to increase its own welfare. Therefore, target shareholders, realizing their value to the acquirer management, will attempt to obtain some of this value. To the extent that target shareholders have some bargaining power, they will succeed in doing so, and the value they obtain will increase with the amount that the acquirer management can appropriate. Therefore, the more severe the agency problem, the higher is the target’s gain. Since greater appropriation by acquirer management also results in lower (or a negative) total gain, the observed gain to acquirer shareholder's should be small (compared to target shareholder's gain) or negative.

R​o​l​l​ ​(​1​9​8​6​) hypothesizes that managers commit errors of over optimism in evaluating takeover opportunities due to excessive pride or hubris. Hence, the takeover premium is a random error, a mistake by the bidder. The hubris hypothesis assumes market efficiency. Stock prices reflect all information; redeployment of productive resources cannot bring gains, and management cannot be improved through reshuffling or combinations across firms. R​o​l​l​ ​(​1​9​8​6​) claims that the hubris hypothesis thus serves as a benchmark for comparison and is the null hypothesis against which other hypotheses should be compared. Further, the hypothesis does not require conscious pursuit of self-interest by managers. Managers may have good intentions, but can make mistakes in judgment.

Since the takeover gain, according to the hubris hypothesis, is presumed to be close to zero, the payment to target shareholders represents a transfer between the target and the acquirer. It follows that the higher the target gain, the lower the bidder gain, and that the total gain is close to zero (e.g., Berkovitch and Narayanan (1993), Malmendier and Tate (2005)).

2.1 The Effect of Deal Characteristics on Bidder Gains

All of the above presented motives suggest that target shareholders experience a gain in takeovers. On the basis of the presented motives, however, the effect for the acquirer firm’s shareholders is not clear. This is also evident in the presented empirical results across different stock markets, where some find positive, some negative and some insignificant bidder returns. The takeover literature has also shown that the characteristics of the deal will affect takeover returns, and, hence, the gain to the shareholders.2

The size of the target company may affect the bidder’s gain. The larger the target company, the larger a potential synergy gain to be split among the parties. However, the larger the target company, the better its negotiation power, and the more difficult the post-integration process. The empirical evidence regarding the relationship is mixed. Kane (2000) and Moeller, Schlingemann and Stulz (2004) argue that large transactions result in value creation for the shareholders. On the other hand, Bradley and Sundaram (2004) show that the announcement effect is more negative with increased target size. As argued by H​a​n​s​e​n​ ​(​1​9​8​7​), a possible revaluation loss will be larger for the bidder the larger the target company. A​l​-​S​h​a​r​k​a​s​ ​(​2​0​0​3​) and T​r​a​v​l​o​s​ ​(​1​9​8​7​) show a negative correlation between bidder abnormal return and relative size. Likewise, T​a​n​g​ ​(​2​0​1​5​) show that acquisitions of small targets generate a larger gain than a combination of similar sized firms. On the other hand, e.g., Asquith, Bruner and Mullins (1983), show that the bidder’s gain increases with the relative size of the target company to the bidder. In this paper we measure the size of the target with the value of the transaction. The relative size is defined as the transaction value to the book value of the bidder prior to the announcement (according to the last quarterly report preceding the announcement).

Cross-border takeovers may open up an opportunity for the bidder to exploit market imperfections and to expand their business into new, international markets (e.g., Moeller and Schlingemann (2005)). Since these effects are unavailable in domestic takeovers, one may expect a higher wealth effect in cross-border deals. Martynova and Renneboog (2008b) argue that takeover gains may be caused by improvements in governance of the bidder and the target firm. However, if there are large institutional differences in the bidder’s and the target’s countries, there may also be difficulties in the post-takeover process to utilize the perceived synergies. If the market anticipates such difficulties it may discount the expected gain. Conn, Cosh, Geust and Hughes (2005) and Moeller and Schlingemann (2005) present evidence consistent with this hypothesis. Mixed results are documented with respect to cross-border acquisitions. However, we expect to find a more positive announcement effect to a cross-border deal. Moeller and Schlingemann (2005) also find a larger positive bidder return if the target is originated in a country with a legal environment offering good shareholder protection. Hence, we also expect a larger positive bidder return for transactions where the target firm is from the US or the UK.

Conglomerate takeovers (diversification) may create operational and financial synergies, which may lower the financial risk, and, hence, the probability that the company goes bankrupt. This may also lower the cost of debt for the company (Agrawal, Jaffe and Mandelker (1992)). Diversification is also associated with a number of disadvantages stemming from the agency problem between managers and shareholders (e.g., Doukas, Holmen and Travos (2002), Schafstein and Stein (2000)), which may lead to lower takeover returns to bidders engaging in conglomerate takeovers. Mixed results have been documented for the value creation to the bidder’s shareholders in conglomerate acquisitions. We expect, however, a more positive announcement response to a focused takeover compared to an announcement of a conglomerate takeover.

The legal status of the target company may also affect the takeover gain. A takeover involving a privately held target company may result in a higher return to the bidder’s shareholders than a corresponding transaction involving a publicly traded target company (e.g., Moeller, Schlingemann and Stulz (2004), Faccio, McConnell and Stolin (2006)). One reason can be a required illiquidity premium, another that the bidder may have a better negotiation power buying a private company compared to launching a public tender offer. The probability of the bid to succeed is also higher in a private transaction. However, buying a private firm can also be considered being more risky, since there is less information available about the target firm. We expect a more positive announcement effect in a takeover transaction involving a privately held target company.

Martynova and Renneboog (2009) suggest that the method of payment may affect the short term market reaction to a takeover announcement. All cash bids are expected to generate a higher return to the shareholders than all-equity bids. The explanation is that asymmetric information implies that the bidder uses shares as a mean of payment when the share is overvalued, and uses cash when it is undervalued (Myers and Majluf (1984)). Several studies have confirmed that the market reaction to announcements of equity offerings is significantly negative (e.g., Moeller, Schlingemann and Stulz (2004), Moeller and Schlingemann (2005), Martynova and Renneboog (2011)). In line with previous studies we expect a more positive announcement effect when the bid is an all-cash offering.

Partial acquisitions (acquisition of less than 100 percent of the target equity) may lead to a higher announcement day return to the bidder than acquisitions aiming for full control. The bidder may use partial acquisitions as an instrument to transfer wealth from the target’s minority shareholders to themselves by, e.g., using pyramid control chains (La Porta, Lopez-de-Silanes, Shleifer and Vishny (2002)). This value extraction is expected to occur more frequently in countries where the minority shareholders are less protected.3

3. Methodology and Data

We study the short-term announcement effect to the bidder’s shareholders and investigate several factors that may affect the stock market reaction to the takeover announcement. We measure the announcement effect as the sum of the daily average abnormal returns4 (CAAR) over different windows around the announcement day5, with a total event window of 41 days, 20 days prior to and 20 days after the event day. We also study alternative event windows before and after the announcement day to capture any effect of a price run-up before the event, or a possible value readjustment after the announcement day. The daily abnormal return (AR) is calculated as the difference between the actual return and the expected return. The expected return is calculated using the market adjusted model, the market model, and the market model with adjusted beta (the estimated beta adjusted for mean reversion (B​l​u​m​e​ ​(​1​9​7​9​)). We use the value-weighted OMX Helsinki cap6 as a proxy for the market portfolio. To estimate the parameters in the market model we use a window of 241 days, starting 300 days and ending 60 days prior to the event day. Our estimates of the abnormal returns are robust with respect to the different choices of the estimation model of the expected returns. Changing the estimation model does not materially change the results, hence, in the remainder of the paper we only report the results using the market model in estimating the expected returns.

To further study the market reaction to the takeover announcement, we regress the bidder’s short term abnormal return on several explanatory factors with respect to the characteristics of the acquisition. The key characteristics we use are the size and the relative size of the transaction, the origin of the target company, the legal status of the target company, the strategic scope of the transaction (focus or diversification), and the mean of payments.

We study a sample of takeovers made by Finnish stock market listed companies during the time period from January 2000 to December 2013. The information about the acquisition is collected from the Thomson ONE Banker Database and corresponding stock exchange releases. There are a total of 1703 acquisitions during the time period where the bidder is publicly traded. We further restrict the sample to acquisitions where the bidder acquire a majority stake in the target (more than 50% ownership), leaving us with 1108 observations. We also eliminate transactions that may be considered too small to yield an observable stock market reaction to the announcement. We set the transaction value limit to 10 million USD, leaving us with a final sample of 314 transactions.

We collect information about the characteristics of the acquisition from the Thomson ONE Banker database, from stock exchange releases and from companies’ homepages. In several acquisitions, when the target firm is privately held, there is a lack of reliable information mostly regarding the term of payments. Some bidders disclose all the details about the bid, but since this is not mandatory for small transactions of privately held targets, there are bidders that do not disclose all details regarding the characteristics of the bid.

Table 1 presents the total sample of 314 takeovers by deal characteristics over the time period January, 2000 – December 2013. The takeover activity was largest in year 2000 (49 transactions) and in the years preceding the financial crises (2005-2007). The mean transaction value is 237 million USD (median 50 million USD). Diversification was the dominant takeover strategy for the bidders in our sample. About 63

Table 1. Descriptive statistics of takeovers in Finland

Year

2000

2001

2002

2003

2004

2005

2006

2007

2008

2009

2010

2011

2012

2013

Total

Total number

49

19

24

14

15

33

36

31

26

13

15

13

16

10

314

% of all

15.61 %

6.05 %

7.64 %

4.46 %

4.78 %

10.51 %

11.46 %

9.87 %

8.28 %

4.14 %

4.78 %

4.14 %

5.10 %

3.18 %

100 %

Value – avg.

317

467

163

63

165

208

122

367

247

260

113

139

262

278

237

Value – max.

4940

3309

1135

186

1735

1482

1191

7954

3188

2404

1128

590

3735

2221

7954

Value – min.

10

10

13

12

11

10

11

10

12

11

13

12

11

13

10

Diversification

29

7

14

8

12

17

28

25

18

7

9

7

12

5

198

% of all

59.18 %

36.84 %

58.33 %

57.14 %

80.00 %

51.52 %

77.78 %

80.65 %

69.23 %

53.85 %

60.00 %

53.85 %

75.00 %

50.00 %

63.06 %

Non-diversification

20

12

10

6

3

16

8

6

8

6

6

6

4

5

116

% of all

40.82 %

63.16 %

41.67 %

42.86 %

20.00 %

48.48 %

22.22 %

19.35 %

30.77 %

46.15 %

40.00 %

46.15 %

25.00 %

50.00 %

36.94 %

Public target

11

4

6

2

1

5

6

7

4

4

0

1

0

0

51

% of all

22.45 %

21.05 %

25.00 %

14.29 %

6.67 %

15.15 %

16.67 %

22.58 %

15.38 %

30.77 %

0.00 %

7.69 %

0.00 %

0.00 %

16.24 %

Non-public target

38

15

18

12

14

28

30

24

22

9

15

12

16

10

263

% of all

77.55 %

78.95 %

75.00 %

85.71 %

93.33 %

84.85 %

83.33 %

77.42 %

84.62 %

69.23 %

100.00

%

92.31 %

100.00

%

100.00

%

83.76 %

Cross-border

31

12

15

8

9

20

20

18

24

7

8

10

11

5

198

% of all

63.27 %

63.16 %

62.50 %

57.14 %

60.00 %

60.61 %

55.56 %

58.06 %

92.31 %

53.85 %

53.33 %

76.92 %

68.75 %

50.00 %

63.06 %

Domestic

18

7

9

6

6

13

16

13

2

6

7

3

5

5

116

% of all

36.73 %

36.84 %

37.50 %

42.86 %

40.00 %

39.39 %

44.44 %

41.94 %

7.69 %

46.15 %

46.67 %

23.08 %

31.25 %

50.00 %

36.94 %

Year

2000

2001

2002

2003

2004

2005

2006

2007

2008

2009

2010

2011

2012

2013

Total

Cash only

10

4

7

3

2

15

10

11

12

5

4

5

6

1

95

% of all

20.41 %

21.05 %

29.17 %

21.43 %

13.33 %

45.45 %

27.78 %

35.48 %

46.15 %

38.46 %

26.67 %

38.46 %

37.50 %

10.00 %

30.25 %

Stock only

13

5

4

3

2

2

0

1

1

4

1

1

0

1

38

% of all

26.53 %

26.32 %

16.67 %

21.43 %

13.33 %

6.06 %

0.00 %

3.23 %

3.85 %

30.77 %

6.67 %

7.69 %

0.00 %

10.00 %

12.10 %

Combined

5

2

1

0

3

2

5

2

1

1

1

2

2

1

28

% of all

10.20 %

10.53 %

4.17 %

0.00 %

20.00 %

6.06 %

13.89 %

6.45 %

3.85 %

7.69 %

6.67 %

15.38 %

12.50 %

10.00 %

8.92 %

Unknown

21

8

12

8

8

14

21

17

12

3

9

5

8

7

153

% of all

42.86 %

42.11 %

50.00 %

57.14 %

53.33 %

42.42 %

58.33 %

54.84 %

46.15 %

23.08 %

60.00 %

38.46 %

50.00 %

70.00 %

48.73 %

100 % acquired

39

17

18

11

12

29

30

24

21

9

13

11

16

9

259

% of all

79.59 %

89.47 %

75.00 %

78.57 %

80.00 %

87.88 %

83.33 %

77.42 %

80.77 %

69.23 %

86.67 %

84.62 %

100.00

%

90.00 %

82.48 %

<100 % acquired

10

2

6

3

3

4

6

7

5

4

2

2

0

1

55

% of all

20.41 %

10.53 %

25.00 %

21.43 %

20.00 %

12.12 %

16.67 %

22.58 %

19.23 %

30.77 %

13.33 %

15.38 %

0.00 %

10.00 %

17.52 %

The table provides information about the characteristics of 314 takeovers with a Finnish acquirer that took place during the time period Jan 2000-Dec 2013. The table provides information about the distribution of takeovers over the sample period, and the distribution of the takeovers partitioned over different characteristics of the acquisition. Value is the value of the bid in million USD, diversification is when the target operates in a different industry than the bidder according to their industry classification (SIC-code), public target is a target company that is publicly traded, cross-border bid is a bid where the target company is of foreign origin, deals classified on the terms of payment (cash, equity, mixed bids and deals with undisclosed terms), and finally, if the bidder acquire 100% of the target or a smaller amount. percent of the bids were for a target company operating in a different industry than the bidder (according to their industry classification). A large proportion of the bids are for privately held target firms (84 percent). The relative number of cross-border bids is 63 percent, with year 2008 as an extreme year with 24 cross- border bids out of a total of 26 bids during that year. This is consistent with the number of cross-border bids (60 percent) for a sample of 53 Finnish bidders during the time period 1993-2001 (Martynova and Renneboog (2011)). Most of the cross-border transactions are for target companies in Sweden (43 transactions). A total of 38 acquisitions are made in countries with the highest shareholder protection (27 transactions in the US and 11 transactions in the UK). The terms of payment are undisclosed in 153 transactions (almost 49 percent). Of the bids for which the payment method is disclosed, the majority is cash bids (30 percent). Of the remaining bids, 38 are all equity bids (12 percent), while 28 bids (9 percent) are a mix of cash and equity. Only about 18 percent (55 transactions) of the bids were partial bids aiming for less than 100 % ownership.

4. Results

In this section we first present the results from the univariate analysis of the bidder’s cumulative average abnormal return (CAAR) in takeover transactions in Finland during the time period from January 2000 to December 2013. Secondly, we analyze the determinants of the abnormal return to the takeover announcement.

Table 2, Panel A shows the descriptive statistics for the abnormal return on the announcement day, the cumulative abnormal return for a seven day event window around the announcement day, and the size related variables used in the analysis. The table shows that the announcement of a takeover bid on average yields a positive abnormal return to the bidder’s shareholders on the announcement day (T = 0). Using the market model7, the average abnormal return (AAR) is about 1.40 percent on the event day. For a longer event windows, seven days centered at the announcement day, the cumulative average abnormal return (CAAR) increases to about 2.14 percent. We also document several extreme cases with both large positive and large negative abnormal returns. The mean transaction value is about 237 million USD (median 50 million), while the relative transaction value (transaction value to the size of the bidder) is about 0.29 (median 0.06). Table 2, Panel B shows the correlation between the variables. There seems to be a negative relationship between the announcement effect and the transaction value. An opposite relationship is evident between the announcement effect and the relative deal value, measured as the value of the transaction to the value of the bidder prior to the announcement.

Panel A reports the descriptive statistics for 314 takeover transactions during the time period Jan 2000-Dec 2013. The average abnormal return (AAR) and the cumulative average abnormal return (CAAR) for a seven day event window is calculated using the market model to estimate the expected return. The market return is calculated using the value-weighted total return index OMX Helsinki cap. The market model parameters are estimated over a period of 241 days starting 300 days before the announcement. TV is the transaction value of the deal in million USD, Relative TV is the relative transaction value of the deal to the value of the bidder. Panel B of Table 2 presents the correlation between the variables. Statistical significance is denoted by */**/*** (10%/5%/1%).

Table 2. Descriptive statistics for 314 takeover transactions

Panel A: Descriptive statistics

AAR (%)

CAAR (%)

TV

Relative TV

Mean

1.40

2.14

237.38

0.29

Median

1.00

2.00

50.68

0.06

Min

-19.84

-29.43

10.04

0.00

Max

69.13

50.96

7953.59

14.07

Std dev

6.02

7.47

702.92

1.01

Panel B: Correlation

AAR

CAAR

LOG(TV)

Relative DV

AAR

1

0.597***

-0.127**

0.591***

CAR

1

-0.100*

0.418***

LOG(TV)

1

0.023

Relative TV

1

Table 3 reports the cumulative abnormal return around the announcement for different event windows ranging from 20 days before to 20 days after the takeover announcement. We document a statistically significant cumulative average abnormal return (CAAR) of about 2 percent for all event windows centered at the announcement day. This result is comparable to the result (CAAR of 2.16 percent for an eleven day event window) reported in Martynova and Renneboog (2011) for a sample of Finnish bidders during the time period 1993-2001.

We do not document any evidence of a price run-up in the pre-event period (20 days to 1 day before the announcement). None of the pre-event windows exhibits a significant CAAR. We do, however, see indications of a delayed market reaction to the announcement with a positive CAAR of 0.57 percent in the event window one day to three days after the announcement. For the longer post-event windows the CAARs are not statistically significant, although there seems to be some price reversal in the longest event window, mainly from days 14 to 20, as is also evident from Figure 1.

The table reports cumulative average abnormal returns for the bidding firms in 314 takeover transactions during the time period Jan 2000-Dec 2013 over different event windows. The expected return is calculated using the market model. The market return is calculated using the value-weighted total return index OMX Helsinki cap. Statistical significance is denoted by */**/*** (10%/5%/1%).

Table 3. Cumulative average abnormal returns (CAARs) for the bidding firms

Market adjusted model

Event window

(%)

(p-value)

Max (%)

Min (%)

[-20. +20]

1.973***

0.009

64.54

-45.29

[-10. +10]

2.083***

0.001

66.33

-46.76

[-5. +5]

2.207***

0.000

54.22

-27.74

[-3. +3]

2.140***

0.000

50.96

-29.43

[-1. +1]

1.888***

0.000

67.25

-23.61

[T=0]

1.398***

0.000

69.13

-19.84

[-20. -1]

0.516

0.366

68.79

-32.64

[-10. -1]

0.231

0.574

36.51

-26.03

[-5. -1]

0.306

0.346

39.17

-24.58

[-3. -1]

0.196

0.467

37.13

-25.86

[+1. +20]

0.060

0.909

52.81

-35.32

[+1. +10]

0.453

0.291

21.67

-45.80

[+1. +5]

0.502

0.142

20.65

-34.74

[+1. +3]

0.566**

0.030

15.17

-22.35

Overall, the results show that short term bidder returns are positive and statistically significant. The returns accumulate mostly during a seven day event window centered at the event day, with the majority of the market reaction to the bid occurring at the announcement day. Hence, the announcement is on average a value creating event for the bidder’s shareholders, indicating that the main motive for the transaction is to create value to the shareholders.8 This is also evident from Table 4, in which we report the number of announcements that yields a positive and a negative market reaction, respectively. Out of the 314 announcements, 202 had a positive abnormal return on the announcement day. However, we cannot rule out that some of the acquisitions are driven by hubris or agency motives, since 112 announcements yielded a negative abnormal announcement day return.

Figure 1. The cumulative abnormal return (CAARs) for the bidding firms

The figure shows the cumulative average abnormal return for the bidding firm in 314 takeover transactions in Finland during the time period Jan 2000-Dec 2013 for an event window of 41 days. The abnormal return is calculated using the market model. The market return is based on the value-weighted total return index OMX Helsinki Cap. The market model parameters are estimated over a period of 241 days starting 300 days before the announcement.

Table 4. Number of positive and negative stock market reactions

Event day [T=0]

CAR [-3,+3]

Number

%

Number

%

Positive

202

64.3

205

65.3

The table reports the number of events with positive and negative abnormal returns in 314 takeover transactions in Finland during the time period Jan 2000-Dec 2013. The abnormal returns are calculated using the market model, where the market return is based on the value-weighted total return index OMX Helsinki cap.

Our results are robust to the choice of estimation model of the benchmark returns and to the length of the event window. In the remainder of the paper we report the results on the announcement day and for an event window of seven days centered at the announcement day using the market model returns as the benchmark returns. Using a longer event window and/or the two alternative estimation models does not materially change the results.9

Table 5. Average abnormal (AAR) and cumulative average abnormal return (CAAR) for the bidding firm by different characteristics of the acquisition

AAR [t=0]

CAAR [-3:3]

(%)

(p-value)

Nobs

(%)

(p-value)

Nobs

Whole sample

1.40 %***

0.00

314

Whole sample

2.14 %***

0.00

314

Large transactions

0.83 %**

0.02

157

Large transactions

2.04 %***

0.00

157

Small transactions

1.97 %***

0.00

157

Small transactions

2.28 %***

0.00

157

Difference

-1.14 %*

0.09

Difference

-0.24 %

0.78

Cross border

0.80 %***

0.01

198

Cross border

1.51 %***

0.00

198

Domestic

2.42 %***

0.00

116

Domestic

3.26 %***

0.00

116

Difference

-1.62 %**

0.02

Difference

-1.75 %**

0.04

US/UK target

1.74 %**

0.04

38

US/UK target

3.05 %**

0.03

38

Other

1.33 %***

0.00

276

Other

2.02 %***

0.00

276

Difference

0.41 %

0.69

Difference

1.03 %

0.46

Diversification

1.80 %***

0.00

198

Diversification

2.55 %***

0.00

198

Non-diversification

0.71 %*

0.06

116

Non-diversification

1.49 %**

0.03

116

Difference

1.09 %

0.12

Difference

1.06 %

0.22

Public target

0.63 %

0.43

51

Public target

0.87 %

0.43

51

Non-public target

1.55 %***

0.00

263

Non-public target

2.41 %***

0.00

263

Difference

-0.92 %

0.32

Difference

-1.54 %

0.18

Cash only

1.19 %***

0.00

95

Cash only

2.50 %***

0.00

95

Other payments

1.49 %***

0.00

219

Other payments

2.01 %***

0.00

219

Difference

-0.29 %

0.69

Difference

0.49 %

0.59

Stock only

3.96 %*

0.08

38

Stock only

4.11 %*

0.07

38

Other payments

1.05 %***

0.00

276

Other payments

1.89 %***

0.00

276

Difference

2.91 %***

0.00

Difference

2.22 %***

0.00

100 % acquired

1.59 %***

0.00

259

100 % acquired

2.27 %***

0.00

259

Less acquired

0.51 %

0.46

55

Less acquired

1.65 %**

0.04

55

Difference

1.08 %

0.23

Difference

0.62 %

0.58

The table reports the average abnormal return and the cumulative average abnormal returns for the bidding firm in 314 takeover transactions in Finland during the time period Jan 2000-Dec 2013 over a seven day event window and for different characteristics of the acquisition. The abnormal returns are calculated using the market model, where the market return is based on the value-weighted total return index OMX Helsinki cap. The acquisition characteristics are the size of the bid, the origin of the target company (cross-border or domestic), the bid being for a publicly traded or privately held company, the bid being for a company within the same industry or for an unrelated company (based upon the SIC-code), the terms of payment; cash or equity, and the bid being non-partial or not. Statistical significance are denoted by */**/*** (10%/5%/1%).

Table 5 reports the market reaction to takeover announcements by deal characteristics. Both large (above median) and small transactions yield a statistically significant abnormal return on the announcement day as well as during the seven day event window. However, large transactions, defined as transactions larger than the median transaction value, seem to yield a lower positive announcement reaction than small transactions on the event day (0.83 versus 1.97 percent). The difference is statistically significant (prob-value 0.09). The difference is, however, insignificant between the two groups during the seven day event window.

Most of the bids made by Finnish bidders are for a foreign target company. Overall, the bidder experience a positive announcement effect for both cross-border and domestic bids, but the announcement effect is significantly lower for bidders engaging in cross-border transactions (0.80 versus 2.42 percent). The same difference is also found in the seven day event window. Bidders making acquisitions in the US or in the UK have a higher announcement effect, and the measured stock market reaction to this type of acquisition is close to the reaction for a domestic acquisition.

Most of the acquisitions made by Finnish bidders are for a target company operating in an unrelated industry, i.e., a diversification takeover. In contrast to our expectations, the announcement of a diversification takeover yields a higher return than an announcement of a related takeover (1.80 versus 0.71 percent on the event day, 2.55 versus 1.49 percent during the seven day event window). The difference is, however, not significant on conventional significance levels.

The announcement of an acquisition of a private target yields a statistically significant abnormal return of 1.55 percent, whereas the announcement of an acquisition of a public target yields a small positive (insignificant) return of 0.63 percent. The same is evident for the seven day event window, i.e., a significant abnormal return in an acquisition of a private target and an insignificant abnormal return in an acquisition of a public target.

We document a statistically significant difference in the announcement effect of stock only versus other types of bids. The announcement effect is significantly higher for stock only bids at the announcement day (3.96 versus 1.05 percent).. Contrary to our expectations there is no difference in the announcement effect of cash versus non-cash bids, but a statistically significant higher announcement effect for all equity bids versus other bids. The results may, though, be affected by the fact that in almost 49 percent of the bids the terms of payment is not disclosed, hence, there may be quite a large number of acquisitions that are misclassified.

Finally, in Table 5, we also report the announcement effect for non-partial versus partial bids. The market response to the announcement is on average slightly positive to both acquisition types, and no significant difference in the response can be detected.

The univariate tests show that there is a difference in the market response to an announcement based upon the characteristics of the bid. In Table 6 we report the results from an OLS-regression of the market reaction using the bid characteristics as explanatory variables. We also add a control variable to the regression, capturing the effect of the sixth takeover wave. For example, J​e​n​s​e​n​ ​(​2​0​0​4​) and Moeller et al. (2005) argue that there is a positive correlation between the sentiment on the stock market and takeover activity, and that bidders in times of high stock market valuation tend to bid more aggressively and, hence, increase the bid premium. As a consequence, the gain that accrues to the bidder’s shareholders decreases. Alexandridis, Mavrovitis and Travlos (2012) defined the sixth takeover wave as the time period between June 2003 and December 2007. However, in Finland the activity on the takeover market did not increase until the beginning of 2005. The increased activity continued until the end of year 2008. To control for a potential effect of this increased activity, we define the sixth takeover wave as the time period between January 2005 and December 2008, and include a dummy variable taking the value 1 if the takeover is announced during that time period. A total of 126 announcements were recorded during this time period.

In the analysis of the market response on the announcement day we see that most of the results from the regression analysis are consistent with the findings in the univariate analysis. Looking at the full model in Table 6, we see that there is a significant negative relationship between the bidder’s abnormal return and the size of the deal, indicating that the market expect that the bidding firm may face large post-acquisition integration costs which will reduce the takeover synergy (Martynova and Renneboog (2011)), or that the acquisition is mainly driven by agency motives or by over optimism. However, looking at the relative size of deal to the value of the bidder we document a statistically significant positive relationship. Hence, the results suggest that the larger the deal is to the value of the bidder, the more likely it is that the transaction is driven by value creation, and that the bidder’s shareholders also capture some part of this gain.

Lower bidder announcement returns are observed for cross-border acquisitions, relative to domestic acquisitions (significant in the seven day event window). The results are consistent with findings reported in Conn et al. (2005) and in Moeller and Schlingemann (2005), indicating that the bidding firm may have difficulties in the post-takeover process to utilize the perceived synergies. However, if the target company is from the US or the UK we observe a statistically significant larger announcement effect.

Table 6. Determinants of the cumulative abnormal return (CAR)

AR [0]

CAR [-3:3]

(1)

(2)

(3)

(1)

(2)

(3)

Dependent variable

coeff.

p-value

coeff.

p-value

coeff.

p-value

coeff.

p-value

coeff.

p-value

coeff.

p-value

Intercept

0.010

0.27

0.012

0.23

0.019***

0.00

0.025*

0.05

0.029**

0.03

0.029***

0.00

LOG(Transaction value)

-0.006***

0.01

-0.006***

0.01

-0.006***

0.01

-0.005

0.13

-0.005

0.14

-0.006*

0.09

Relative deal value

0.035***

0.00

0.035***

0.00

0.036***

0.00

0.031***

0.00

0.031***

0.00

0.031***

0.00

Cross-border

-0.009

0.16

-0.009

0.17

-0.009

0.18

-0.015*

0.06

-0.013*

0.09

-0.015*

0.07

USUK target

0.015*

0.05

0.014*

0.05

0.015*

0.07

0.023*

0.06

0.023**

0.04

0.028*

0.07

Public target

-0.003

0.70

-0.003

0.70

-0.013

0.28

-0.011

0.35

Diversification

0.008

0.16

0.009

0.14

0.009

0.24

0.008

0.26

Acquiring 100 % of shares

0.002

0.80

0.002

0.82

-0.004

0.65

-0.005

0.58

Cash only

0.002

0.68

0.001

0.78

0.011

0.19

0.009

0.28

Stock only

-0.025

0.86

-0.004

0.74

-0.003

0.85

-0.007

0.68

Sixth wave

0.004

0.46

0.001

0.84

F-stat.

18.84***

0.00

26.99***

0.00

30.99***

0.00

8.05***

0.00

11.22***

0.00

13.06***

0.00

Adjusted R²

0.363

0.368

0.365

0.184

0.186

0.188

Number of acquisitions

314

314

314

314

314

314

The table reports the results of the OLS regression of the cumulative abnormal return for the bidders in 314 takeover transactions in Finland during the time period Jan 2000-Dec 2013. LOG(Transaction value) is the value of the bid in million USD, relative deal value is the relative value of the deal to the value of the bidder, cross-border is a dummy variable taking the value 1 when the target company is of foreign origin, USUK target is a dummy variable taking the value 1 when the target company is from the US or the UK, public target is a dummy variable taking the value 1 when the target company is publicly traded, diversification is a dummy variable taking the value 1 when the target operates in a different industry than the bidder according to their industry classification (SIC-code), acquiring 100 % of shares is a dummy variable taking the value of 1 if the bidder acquires all shares, cash only is a dummy variable taking the value 1 when the acquisition is paid for in cash, stock only is a dummy variable taking the value 1 when the acquisition is paid for in stock and sixth wave is a dummy variable taking the value 1 if the acquisition takes place during the time period January 2005 to December 2008. All regressions contain White’s heteroskedastic-consistent standard errors. Statistical significance are denoted by */**/*** (10%/5%/1%).

There are indications of the market perceiving diversification announcements to be good news, rewarding the bid with a higher positive (not significant) abnormal return than a corresponding announcement of a focused acquisition. Hence, the investors consider the positive effect of risk reduction being larger than the negative effect of the agency problem.

In the univariate analysis there were some indications of a lower bidder abnormal return when the target company is publicly listed. We also documented a positive announcement effect for stock only bids versus other types of bids. However, in the multivariate setting these differences disappear, indicating that the results may be driven by size related issues instead. There is no difference in the announcement effect whether the bidder acquire 100 percent of the target or a smaller amount. The control variable for the sixth takeover wave is also insignificant.

Finally, in Table 6, we also report the results from different specifications of the model. In model specification two we exclude the term of payments variables and the takeover wave dummy, and in specification three we exclude the public target, diversification, non-partial and the takeover wave dummy. The alternative specifications do not change the estimated coefficients for the size related variables or the target origin related variables.

5. Conclusions

In this study, we analyze the short term market reactions to takeover announcements in a sample of 314 acquisitions made by a stock market listed Finnish company during the time period from January 2000 to December 2013. The acquisitions of Finnish companies during the studied period were characterized by a diversification strategy involving a foreign target company. The acquisition was typically friendly, and aimed for the entire capital of the target company. We document, on average, a significant positive stock market reaction to the announcement. The announcement effect is statistically significant yielding an average abnormal return of 1.4 percent on the announcement day. This result is consistent with the assumption that most of the acquisitions are motivated by synergy. Neither the pre-event nor the post-event abnormal returns are statistically significant, although there is sign of a negative price revaluation in the post-event period.

We also investigate the relationship between the market reaction to the announcement and deal characteristics. We document a significant, negative relationship between deal size and the abnormal return on the announcement day. However, looking at the size of the deal in relation to the size of the bidder we find a reversed relationship, i.e., the larger the relative size of the deal, the more positive the announcement effect. The market reaction is more favorable to an acquisition of a domestic target company, indicating that the market believes that the acquirer may face substantial post-acquisition integration costs in cross-border transactions. If the target company is from the US or from the UK the negative cross-border effect is smaller. We also document that an acquisition motivated by diversification may yield a higher abnormal return to the bidder shareholders than an acquisition of a target firm within the same industry. Hence, the decrease in the financial risk seems to be more important than a potential increase in the agency costs. We do not find any significant relationship between the announcement effect and legal status of the target, the terms of payment, full acquisition of the target, or the sixth takeover wave.

Data Availability

The data used to support the findings of this study are available from the corresponding author upon request.

Acknowledgments

An early version of this paper was presented at the 11th International Scientific Conference on Economic and Social Development – Building Resilient Society, Zagreb, Croatia.

Conflicts of Interest

The authors declare that they have no conflicts of interest.

References
Agrawal, A. and Jaffe, J. (2000). The post-merger performance puzzle. Advances in Mergers and Acquisitions 1, 7-41.
Agrawal, A., Jaffe, J. and Mandelker, G. (1992). The post-merger performance of acquiring firms: a re-examination of an anomaly. Journal of Finance 47, 1605-1621.
Alexandridis, G., Mavrovitis, C. and Travlos, N. (2012). How have MandAs changed? Evidence from the sixth merger wave. European Journal of Finance 18, 663-688.
Al-Sharkas, A. (2003). Shareholder wealth effect in bank mergers: new evidence during the period 1980-2000. In 2003 Proceedings from AFFI, Paris. [Google Scholar]
Amihud, Y. and Lev, B. (1981). Risk reduction as a managerial motive for conglomerate mergers. Bell Journal of Economics 12, 605-617.
Auerbach, A. and Reishaus, D. (1987). The effects of taxation on the merger decision. National Bureau of Economic Research, Working paper.
Asquith, P., Bruner, R. F. and Mullins, D.W. (1983). The gains to bidding firms from mergers. Journal of Financial Economics 11, 121-139.
Berkovitch, E. and Narayanan, M. (1993). Motives for takeovers: an empirical investigation. Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis 28, 347-362. [Google Scholar]
Blume, M. (1979). Betas and their regression tendencies: some further evidence. Journal of Finance 34, 265-267. [Google Scholar]
Bradley, M., Desai, A. and Kim, H.E. (1988). Synergistic gains from corporate acquisitions and their division between the stockholders of target and acquiring firms. Journal of Financial Economics 21, 3-40.
Bradley, M and Sundaram, A. (2004). Do acquisitions drive performance or does performance drive acquisitions? SSRN Working paper.
Bruner, R. (2004). Does MandA pay? Applied Mergers and Acquisitions 1, 11-15.
Chappell, H. and Cheng, D. (1984). Firms’ acquisition decisions and Tobin’s Q ratio. Journal of Economics and Business 2, 29-42.
Conn, R., Cosh, A., Guest, P. and Hughes, A. (2005). The impact on UK acquiriers of domestic, cross-border, public and private acquisitions. Journal of Business Finance and Accounting 32, 815-870.
Dennis, D. and McConnell, J. (1986). Corporate mergers and security returns. Journal of Financial Economics 16, 143-187.
Dodd, P. and Ruback, R. (1977). Tender offers and shareholders returns: an empirical analysis. Journal of Financial Economics 5, 351-374. [Google Scholar]
Doukas, J., Holmen, M. and Travlos, N. (2002). Diversification, ownership, and control of Swedish corporations. European Financial Management 8, 281-314.
Eckbo, E. (1992). Mergers and the value of antitrust dererrence. Journal of Finance 47, 1005-1029.
Faccio, M., McDonnell, J. and Stolin, D. (2006). Returns to acquirers of listed and unlisted targets. Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis 41, 197-220.
Fishman, M. (1988). A theory of preemptive takeover bidding. Rand Journal of Economics 19, 88-101. [Google Scholar]
Galai, D. and Masulis, R. (1976). The option pricing model and the risk factor of stock. Journal of Financial Economics 4, 53-82.
Goergen, M., Martynova, M. and Renneboog, L. (2005). Corporate governance convergence: evidence from takeover regulation reforms. Oxford Review of Economic Policy 21, 243-268. [Google Scholar]
Goergen, M. and Renneboog, L. (2004). Shareholders wealth effects of European domestic and cross-border bids. European Financial Management 10, 9-45.
Grossman, S. and Hart, O. (1980). Takeover bids, the free rider problem, and the theory of the corporation. Bell Journal of Economics 11, 42-64.
Hamza, T. (2011). Determinants of short-term value creation for the bidder: evidence from France. Journal of Management and Governance 15, 157-186. [Google Scholar]
Hansen, R. (1987). A theory for the choice of exchange medium in mergers and acquisitions. Journal of Business 60, 75-95. [Google Scholar]
Harris, E. (1990). Anti-takeover measures, golden parachutes, and target firm shareholder welfare. Rand Journal of Economics 21, 614-625. [Google Scholar]
Högfeldt, P. and Högholm, K. (2000). A law and finance theory of strategic blocking and preemptive bidding in takeovers. Journal of Corporate Finance 6, 403-425.
Israel, R. (1992). Capital and ownership structures, and the market for corporate control. The Review of Financial Studies 5, 181-198. [Google Scholar]
Jarrell, G., Brickley, J. and Netter, J. (1988). The market for corporate control: the empirical evidence since 1980. Journal of Economic Perspectives 2, 49-68. [Google Scholar]
Jensen, M. (1986). Agency cost of free cash flow, corporate finance and takeovers. American Economic Review 76, 323-329. [Google Scholar]
Jensen, M. (2004). The agency cost of overvalued equity and the current state of corporate finance. European Financial Management 10, 549-565. [Google Scholar]
Jensen, M. andMeckling, W. (1976). Theory of the firm: managerial behavior, agency costs and ownership structure. Journal of Financial Economics 3, 305-360. [Google Scholar]
Jensen, M. and Ruback, R. (1983). The market for corporate control: the scientific evidence. Journal of Financial Economics 11, 5-50. [Google Scholar]
Kane, E. (2000). Incentives for banking megamergers: what motives might regulators infer from event-study evidence? Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 32, 671-701.
La Porta, R., Lopez-de-Silanes, F., Shleifer, A. and Vishny, R. (2002). Investor protection and corporate valuation. Journal of Finance 57, 1147-1170.
Lakonishok, J., Shleifer, A. and Vishny, R. (1994). Contrarian investment, extrapolation, and risk. Journal of Finance 49, 1541-1578.
Levy, H. and Sarnat, M. (1970). Diversification, portfolio analysis and the uneasy case for conglomerate mergers. Journal of Finance 25, 795-802.
Malmendier, U. and Tate, G. (2005). Does overconfidence affect corporate investment? CEO overconfidence measures revisited. European Financial Management 11, 649-659.
Martynova, M. and Renneboog, L. (2008a). A century of corporate takeovers: what have we learned and where do we stand? Journal of Banking and Finance 32, 2148-2177. [Google Scholar]
Martynova, M. and Renneboog, L. (2008b). Spillover of corporate governance standards in cross-border mergers and acquisitions. Journal of Corporate Finance 14, 200-223.
Martynova, M. and Renneboog, L. (2009). What determines the financing decision in corporate takeovers: cost of capital, agency problems or the means of payment? Journal of Corporate Finance 15, 290-315. [Google Scholar]
Martynova, M. and Renneboog, L. (2011). The performance of the European market for corporate control: evidence from the fifth takeover wave. European Financial Management 17, 208-259. [Google Scholar]
Moeller, S. and Schlingemann, F. (2005). Global diversification and bidder gains: a comparison between cross-border and domestic acquisitions. Journal of Banking and Finance 29, 533-564. [Google Scholar]
Moeller, S., Schlingemann, F. and Stulz, R. (2004). Firm size and the gain from acquisitions. Journal of Financial Economics 73, 201-228.
Moeller, S., Schlingemann, F. and Stulz, R. (2005). Wealth destruction on a massive scale? A study of acquiring-firm returns in the recent merger wave. Journal of Finance 60, 757-782.
Morck, R., Shleifer, A. and Vishny, R.W. (1990). Do managerial objectives drive bad acquisitions? Journal of Finance 45, 31-48.
Myers, S. and Majluf, N. (1984). Corporate financing and investment decisions when firms have information that investors do not have. Journal of Financial Economics 13, 187-221.
Prescott, E. and Visscher, M. (1980). Organization capital. Journal of Political Economy 88, 446-461.
Rau, R. and Vermaelen, T. (1998). Glamour, value and post-acquisition performance of acquiring firms. Journal of Financial Economics 49, 223-253.
Roll, R. (1986). The hubris hypothesis of corporate takeovers. The Journal of Business 59, 197-216. [Google Scholar]
Scharfstein, D. and Stein, J. (2000). The dark side of internal capital markets: divisional rent-seeking and inefficient investment. Journal of Finance 55, 2537-2564. [Google Scholar]
Shleifer, A. and Summers, L. (1988). Breach of trust in hostile takeovers. In Corporate takeovers: causes and consequences, University of Chicago Press, Chicago. [Google Scholar]
Shleifer, A. and Vichny, R. (1989). Managerial entrenchment: the case of managerial-specific investments. Journal of Financial Economics 25, 123-139. [Google Scholar]
Stulz, R., Walking, R. and Song, M. (1990). The distribution of target ownership and the division of gains in successful takeovers. Journal of Finance 45, 817-833.
Sudarsanam, S. and Mahate, A. (2003). Glamour acquirers, method of payment and post-acquisition performance: the UK evidence. Journal of Business Finance and Accounting 30, 299-341.
Summer, C. (1980). Strategic behavior in business and government. Little, Brown and Company, Boston. [Google Scholar]
Tang, T. (2015). Bidder’s gain: Evidence from termination returns. International Review of Finance, 15, 457-487. [Google Scholar]
Travlos, N. G. (1987). Corporate takeover bids, methods of payment, and bidding firms’ stock returns. Journal of Finance 42, 943-963. [Google Scholar]
Williamson, O. (1975). Markets and hierarchies: analysis and antitrust implications. Free press, New York. [Google Scholar]

Cite this:
APA Style
IEEE Style
BibTex Style
MLA Style
Chicago Style
GB-T-7714-2015
Högholm, K. & Knif, J. (2016). Short Term Announcement Returns to the Bidder**. J. Corp. Gov. Insur. Risk Manag., 3(2), 17-45. https://doi.org/10.56578/jcgirm030202
K. Högholm and J. Knif, "Short Term Announcement Returns to the Bidder**," J. Corp. Gov. Insur. Risk Manag., vol. 3, no. 2, pp. 17-45, 2016. https://doi.org/10.56578/jcgirm030202
@research-article{Högholm2016ShortTA,
title={Short Term Announcement Returns to the Bidder**},
author={Kenneth HöGholm and Johan Knif},
journal={Journal of Corporate Governance, Insurance, and Risk Management},
year={2016},
page={17-45},
doi={https://doi.org/10.56578/jcgirm030202}
}
Kenneth HöGholm, et al. "Short Term Announcement Returns to the Bidder**." Journal of Corporate Governance, Insurance, and Risk Management, v 3, pp 17-45. doi: https://doi.org/10.56578/jcgirm030202
Kenneth HöGholm and Johan Knif. "Short Term Announcement Returns to the Bidder**." Journal of Corporate Governance, Insurance, and Risk Management, 3, (2016): 17-45. doi: https://doi.org/10.56578/jcgirm030202
Högholm K., Knif J.. Short Term Announcement Returns to the Bidder**[J]. Journal of Corporate Governance, Insurance, and Risk Management, 2016, 3(2): 17-45. https://doi.org/10.56578/jcgirm030202
cc
undefined